ECON 201 - Principles of
Economics:
Intro. to MICROECONOMICS
Phil Martinez, Economics
A Brief History of
Microeconomic Theory
Introduction
Contemporary
microeconomics uses mathematical models to represent
the ideal behavior of individual consumers and
producers in a theoretical market. While these models
rely upon the perfectly logical causal implications of
mathematics, they are based upon and incorporate ideas
that came before the use of modern mathematical
modeling. Contemporary microeconomics has its roots in
Adam Smith’s theory of the free market (c. mid 1770s)
and in the Utilitarians’ theory of human behavior (c.
mid 1800s).
Adam Smith and the
Theory of the Free Market (c. mid 1700s)
In his book, An
Inquiry into the Nature and Cause of the Wealth of
Nations, Adam Smith constructed the theory of the free
market. In this theory Smith attempts to explain how
an unregulated (i.e. “free”) market can generate
new wealth and benefits to society that outstrip any
previous economic system (i.e. feudalism) or any
conceivable new economic system.
He theorized
that in an unregulated (i.e. “free) market individuals
are able to pursue their own self-interest.
The pursuit of
self-interest generates economic competition.
According to Smith's view, competition is generated in
all markets throughout the economy. It is generated
among consumers for access to employment and goods,
among producers for access to resources and to
markets, and between consumers and producers over the
distribution of the benefits from transactions.
Competition in turn
generates the independent adjustment of prices.
If the quantity demanded of a good is greater the
quantity supplied of the good the current market
price, then market price will independently rise. If
the quantity supplied of a good is greater the
quantity demanded of the good the current market
price, then market price will independently fall. The
independent adjustment of prices is the most important
process in the market mechanism, i.e. in the demand
and supply process.
These independent price
adjustments continue until an equilibrium is
generated where the quantity demand of the
good exactly equals the quantity supplied of the good
at a single market price.
Smith concludes
that when equlibrium occurs the market has achieved a
series of beneficial
results:
(i) Efficiency.
There are three
different but inter-related concepts of efficiency all
of which occur at equilibrium:
• Economic
Efficiency: producing the maximum economic
(or financial) return from a given set of economic (or
financial) resources), for example from a given amount
of investment.
• Productive
Efficiency: producing the maximum output from
a given set of productive resources (i.e. inputs).
This means there is no waste or pollution occurring.
Any residual (leftover) resources have no productive
use and do no harm.
• Allocative
Efficiency: producing the optimal mix of
outputs from society’s resources. All of society’s
resources are being used to produce the most desired
goods consistent with consumer’s preferences. There is
no under-production or over-production of any good in
the economy and every production process is efficient.
So every resource is allocated to its best possible
use.
(ii) Social Optimality
Adam Smith
theorized that since individuals pursuing their
self-interest in the unregulated market could freely
enter into fair and balanced transactions (i.e. no one
in the market had any power to manipulate prices or
output, or force specific conditions on anyone else in
the market) then each person was assured to gain the
maximum benefit for themselves in every transaction
that they entered. Otherwise they would not agree to
the terms of the transaction. They would simply go on
to a more beneficial transaction. Since everyone was
engaged in such transactions the unregulated market
would generate the maximum benefits for everyone
partaking in the market. Society based upon an
unregulated market would produce the maximum benefits.
Pareto
Optimality. While this is a very reassuring
theory (people everywhere have always wanted to
believe that their society is the best even in the
face of contrary evidence) economists have only been
able to establish that the market is able to generate
a Pareto Optimality. This occurs when no one can gain
any additional benefits unless someone else in the
economy loses some benefits. In other words, all of
the benefits have been distributed. Every piece of the
pie has been distributed to someone. The only way for
a Pareto optimal situation to be improved upon is for
the pie to grow larger and more becomes available to
distribute.
The problem
with Pareto Optimality is that it is an extremely weak
concept of what is social best. In fact, it does not
meet the basic concepts of democratic fairness, since
it cannot distinguish a democracy as being better than
a brutal dictatorship.
Imagine a
country that produces $100,000 and has population of
100 people. The dictator receives $90,000 and hires
and arms a military of 9 people to force the rest of
the population to work. The military receives $1000
each. The remaining 90 people have $1000 to share
between them. Note that not one worker can earn even
$1 more unless someone else loses $1. Even taking a
dollar from the dictator to give to a worker would not
be considered a Pareto improvement since the dictator
has to lose $1.
This an
important point in understanding how Neoclassical
microeconomic theory functions and how it has been
misused. The laissez-faire doctrine which argues
that an unregulated market always produces a better
result than a regulated market is, perhaps. the most
common misapplication of Neoclassical microeconomic
theory. The laissez-faire doctrine can only be shown
to produce Pareto optimality not the broader concepts
social optimality or democratic fairness.
(iii) Consumer Sovereignty
Smith concludes
that at market equilibrium producers have produced
only those goods most desired by demanders. The point
is that producers do not choose what to produce
leaving consumers only the choice of what to pick out
of range of possibly less desired goods, for example
production under the former Soviet system. Rather,
producers respond to what consumers are willing and
able to spend money on. Therefore, consumers determine
what is most needed and desired for the society, and
producers respond with the most efficient way to
produce it.
(iv) Uniqueness
Smith’s theory
of the free market concludes that there is only a
single equilibrium – single most efficient, socially
best, solution to any economic problem.
Market Imperfections
and Market Failures
Smith was aware of a couple of potential problems in
the Free Market Theory. One area he was concerned
about was the tendency for producers to try to collude
to set prices to avoid competition.
"People of the same trade
seldom meet together, even for merriment and diversion,
but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the
public, or in some contrivance to raise prices."
Another area was what he called "public works", goods
that were beneficial to be provided to the society as
a whole but which no individual producer would have an
incentive or ability to provide. For Smith these
included roads, bridges, and public education.
Since Smith's time economists have come to analyze
both of these areas and to identify a few others that
Smith could not have known about. These
characteristics of markets are now common and well
understood. When they occur in actual markets then the free market
will fail to generate the beneficial outcomes. Additionally, when we
alter the free market models to include these
imperfect market conditions then the models generate
results that more accurately reflect actual markets
rather than ideal markets. That is the under these
imperfect conditions the market will fail to acheive
the efficient, optimal, unique equilibrium theorized
by Smith. We classify these market conditions as
market imperfections and market failures.
Market imperfections occur when there is some
inherent problem with the pricing function of the
market. In this case the free market will produce the
good at an equilibrioum price and quantity, however,
that price and quantity will not be
the efficient, optimal price and quantity. Categories
of market imperfections are market power (i.e. monopoly,
oligopoly, et cetera); externalities; and imperfect information.
Smith's concern about price collusion in the comment
above is an example of a market imperfection.
Market
failures occur when the market is unable to
produce a good or service at all under competitive
conditions. With market failures the market is
entirely unable to generate a price, or cannot
generate a competitive price and ensure that they are
paid by every consumer. When these conditions exist
either the government must provide the goods directly,
or the government must allow a private monopoly to
produce the goods under heavy regulation and with
guarantees of profit rates that approximate a
competitive market. The primary category of
market failures is called public goods. Smith's "public works" -
roads, bridges, public education - are examples of
public goods.
Another area that our textbook (The Economy Today,
Schiller) includes as a market failure is the issue of
equity. The
free market will not provide any goods for anyone who
cannot pay the market price for the good.
Additionally, the free market will not employ and
provide an income to anyone who is not actively
employed. Thus, the free market is guaranteed to
starve to death all those who are unable to work and
provide for their own care - orphans, disabled,
mentally ill, seniors, et cetera. These conditions
violate all modern standards of fairness (i.e.
equity), especially in democracies. Thus, the free
market cannot produce economic equity.
The Utilitarianian Theory of Human
Behavior (c. mid 1800s)
The Utilitarians were a leading group of philiosphers
of the mid 1800s who argued that there was a
fundamental theory that exlained all human behavior.
According to the Utilitarians all human behavior
conformed to the "pleasure-pain principle". All human
behavior was said to be motivated by the pursuit of
pleasure and avoidance of pain. This became important
to economic theory because it was a
specific interpretation of Smith's claim that in
an unregulated market people pursue their
self-interest. Under the Utilitarians' interpretation
"pursuing self-interest" meant seeking the maximum
pleasure and minimum pain in all endeavors, or in
economic terms, in all transactions.
The Marginalists, aka
Neoclassicals, and Utility Maximization (c. late
1800s to present)
The Marginalists (now-a-days caled Neoclassicals) made
the final step in translating Smith's Theory of the
Free Market into a set of mathematical models. By
recognizing that "seeking maximum pleasure and minimum
pain" could be easily formulated as a calculus
constrained maximization problem they began writing
mathematical models (systems of equations) to
represent the essence of Smith's Free Market Theory.
They developed the mathematical methods and structure
that are now used in most microeconomic theory.
(i) Utility Maximization
Specifically, they modelled all economic actors as
making choices based upon seeking to maximize the
utility (i.e. benefit) gained from their choices
within the limits of their resources (budget, income,
endowment).
Consumers are modelled as seeking to maximize the
utility of their purchases limited by their budget (or
income).
Producers are modelled as seeking to maximize profit
limited by their technology.
Government is modelled as seeking to maximize total
public benefit limited by its budget (or available
resources).
Note that for producers we use slightly different
terminology, the words "profit" and "technology". We
do this only to be more specific. In the case of
consumers we assume some theoretical benefit called
"utility" since we cannot state precisely what
consumers maybe trying to achieve with any specific
choice or purchase. In the case of producers we can be
more specific since producers must seek a profit in
order to be successful. Similarly we use the term
"technology" instead of "budget" to emphasize that a
producer is making a decision based upon a specific
production process or enterprise. A budget, or
investment, or set of costs fund a production process
but do not in themselves produce anything. They must
first be spent on or invested in a productive process,
which we call "technology".
(ii) Economic Rationality
When we model human decision-making behavior with
mathematics we represent human behavior as being just
as logical as the mathematics. We have little choice
in this since mathematics is perfectly logical and
internally consistent. Thus if we use mathematics to
represent human choices we are necessarily limiting
the choices to only the mathematically logical
results. For example, while Sara might always prefer
apple pie over cherry pie, she may occasionally choose
a piece of cherry instead of the apple pie for random,
emotional, unconscious, or other inconsistent reasons.
This is not an option in mathematics. If 6 is greater
than 5, then 6 must always be greater than 5 in all
calculations. For this reason we model all of our
economic decisionmakers in microeconomic models as
being perfectly consistent (i.e. economically
rational) in all their choices.
An "economically rational" person:
- is a
utility maximizer;
- and
can rank or prioritize all of their preferences
over all alternative goods or options.
So note that we
have now translated Smith's idea of "individuals
pursuing self-interest" into a mathematical model of
"utility maximizers who prioritize all of the
preferences".
“The theory of rational behavior is
usually presented as a study of the
principals upon which a rational man would
act. This rational man...makes no errors in
arithmetic, or logic, in attempting to
achieve his clearly defined
objectives...Every action is perfectly
thought out; every risk is perfectly
calculated.”
Harry Markowitz (the
father of modern investment portfolio
theory)
|
(iii) The Utility
Maximization Model and Actual Behavior
It is important to
remember that a model is not a description of actual
phenomena, but a tool to help us think about the
actual phenomena. Thus, a model can be unrealistic in
many ways but still valuable in helping us to identify
fundamental relationships, forces, tendencies, or
possible outcomes of actual phenomena.
Given what we know about cognitive
psychology, utility maximization is a
ludicrous concept; equilibrium pretty foolish
outside of financial markets; perfect
competition a howler for most industries. The
reason for making these assumptions is not
that they are reasonable but that they seem to
help us produce models that are helpful
metaphors for things that we think happen in
the real world.
How I Work
Paul Krugman, PhD
Prof.
of
Economics
&
Int'l
Affairs,
Princeton University
|
(iv) Irrationality and
Behavioral Economics
Just as market
imperfections and market failures are common economic
conditions that show free market theory to be an
overally narrow model, contemporary psychology
provides considerable evidence that humans do not
behave nor make decisions like the free market theory
assumes. In other words, the assumption of a a
rational, perfectly logical, self-interested,
maximizing decisionmaker is inaccurate. Economists who
are attempting to analyze how people actually make
decisions and to include this process in economic
models and theory are called Behavioral Economists.
One of the leading Behavioral Economists is Dan
Ariely, author of Predictably
Irrational (which I highly recommend
for students interested in delving into current
cutting edge economics). Below I've placed several
video links to YouTube videos of Dr. Ariely explaining
how humans actually make decisions and why the free
market models of traditional free market theory are
such poor tools.
Before you check out Dan's videos let me provide two
explanatory points. First, as a young man Dan was an
Israeli soldier and survived a bomb blast, which
burned 70% of his body. This experience is relevant
because it started him on this path of economic
research, as he explains in one of the videos.
Secondly, when he states in the videos that "there are
free lunches" he is criticising the Neoclassical
assumption that the market always generates the
efficient, optimal outcome. In Neoclassical economics
we often state that "there are no free lunches", as
short hand for saying all goods are properly priced,
all costs are properly accounted for, and the free
market produces at maximum efficiency. By claiming
there are free lunches he is saying that by
acknowledging that we are not rational, and changing
our behavior to be more rational or implementing rules
to make us behave rationally, we can actually increase
efficiency without sacrificing any additional
resources. More rational behavior results in less
waste and error, so we get more output and more
efficiency for the same resources used. There are free
lunches.
Irrational
Predictability, Dan Ariely, FORA.tv, 2008
Irrationality
and Self-Control, Dan Ariely, TED Lecture, 2008
Cheating
and Group Behavior, Dan Ariely, TED Lecture, 2009
|